<%@ Language=VBScript %> <% CheckState() CheckSub() %> Chasing a Ghost: Retail Power and the Development of Slotting Allowances in the United States Food Sector: an Historical Perspective
Journal of Advertising History

Journal of Advertising History

History of Advertising Trust
Unit 6, The Raveningham Centre, Raveningham, Norwich NR14 6NU
Tel: +44 (0) 1508 548 623, Fax: +44 (0) 1508 548 478

Special Issue, 2002


Chasing a Ghost: Retail Power and the Development of Slotting Allowances in the United States Food Sector: an Historical Perspective

Roger A. Dickinson,
University of Texas at Arlington

INTRODUCTION

Slotting allowances in their most basic form are one-time payments made by suppliers to retailers related to the introduction of new products. They may also be considered one of a family of related marketing practices that include presentation fees, slotting allowances or fees, display fees, pay-to-stay fees, and failure fees (Bloom et al. 2000, 93). Slotting allowances are a one-time event, whereas pay-to-stay fees may make the incidence of slotting allowances substantially longer term1. Although slotting allowances have been with us for many years, they had become regarded as of some significance in the food industry by the mid-1980s (Bloom et al. 2000).

A substantial segment of the marketing literature associates the development of slotting allowances in the food sector with an increased power of retailers (Cannon & Bloom 1991; Bloom et al. 2000; Ailawadi 2001). Bloom et al. (2000) also offer evidence that retailers and suppliers do perceive a relationship between slotting allowances and an increased power of retailers. However, the perceived increase in retail power may have been an illusion. In the years preceding the development of slotting allowances, retailers were powerful, but they were restrained in their bargaining behaviour by the Robinson-Patman Act of 1936 (often called the Anti-A&P Act) and related statutes. Indeed, at one time the A&P retail food giant required suppliers to indicate in writing that discounts offered to them had also been generally available to other retailers.

This article may be seen as offering a case in which a lack of understanding of the historical development of negotiation in the food industry and the attendant evolution of the legal framework may have substantially influenced public policy and academic studies. In essence we may have been chasing a ghost, and at substantial costs, including opportunity costs. Our framework for approaching slotting allowances may have distorted our perspective of the problem. This article:

  1. Describes slotting allowances;

  2. Considers retail power;

  3. Delineates some basics of the Robinson-Patman Act;

  4. Describes a scenario in which slotting allowances could have come about;

  5. Indicates some possible ramifications of the suggested change in perspective.

SLOTTING ALLOWANCES

Slotting allowances are one of the many elements in a bundle of supplier promotional alternatives. From one perspective promotional activities are primarily developed by suppliers on their own as a means of increasing their profitability over some time frame. From another perspective supplier offerings are strongly influenced by the large retailers. Ailawadi (2001) makes the judgement that sales promotions can be just as profitable for the supplier as for the retailer. Indeed, in some instances one can see substantial supplier research expenditures with respect to shelf space allocation of a specific retailer for a new product as an element in supplier promotion and used by suppliers to achieve most of the objectives of slotting allowances in gaining competitive advantage. Steiner (2001) recently maintained that being a channel captain offered a supplier a method of enhancing its position and perhaps was conducive to a variety of collusive arrangements. The number of promotional alternatives within a supplier budget can be very large.

Retailers have basically justified slotting allowances on the basis of the increased cost to retailers of dealing with a continuous and increasing flow of new products from suppliers (Lariviere & Padmanabhan 1997). Suppliers often see the allowances as ‘extorted’ by the retailer in the use of ‘raw power’.

The negotiation of slotting allowances in the food industry between large buyers and large sellers (small buyers and sellers may also be relevant to slotting allowances) may be seen as a way in which an oligopsonist tries to make the offerings of an oligopolist more favourable. In this view, slotting allowances may be usefully compared to the practice of industrial reciprocity in industrial purchasing2. In the traditional form of industrial reciprocity large industrial firm A keeps track of its purchases from other firms, e.g. firm B. If firm A perceives any residual power as a result of its large purchases from B, it can try to ‘force’ supplier firm B to purchase other goods/services from it, one of its divisions and so on. In this view retailers are exercising power in an effort to neutralise the power of the oligopolist to set price and/or other the terms of the transaction or relationship.

The study of buyer-seller relations in many industries is made difficult because the terms of trade are not generally available to the public. Most buyers and sellers are reluctant to reveal the terms of relationships because of the business considerations and because of the possible legal implications (typically the relevant laws are not understood by the buyer or seller (Dickinson 1967b)). Therefore, little specific is known with respect to slotting allowance behaviour and other terms of trade. In general, retailers have been more close-lipped about slotting allowances than suppliers (Bloom et al. 2000).

RETAIL POWER

We know that power counts in determining many dimensions of buyer-seller relationships, constrained in certain circumstances by the law. The logic of the situation suggests this. Further, there is an inverse association between the margins of manufacturers and retailers (Steiner 1984).

Unfortunately with respect to discussions about retail power versus supplier power, power in the channel is difficult to define (Dickinson & Hollander 1996). Does power that a retailer has with respect to the consumer translate directly into power with respect to the supplier? Is there such a thing as a power of retailers in general or is most power reflected in one-to-one retailer-supplier interactions? If power is an individual buyer-seller matter between one supplier and one retailer, can these ‘individual powers’ be ‘summed’ to reach a conclusion with respect to changes in retail power in defined merchandise classifications? Perhaps one can take measures of profitability for defined retail-supplier classifications (categories) and compare trends in overall profitability, or perhaps return on investment (Farris & Ailawadi 1992; Ailawadi 2001). Of course, any one measure of power has problems. For example, overall profitability is created by myriad factors, some perhaps not even ascertainable.

Here we do not directly define power between retailers and suppliers, but suggest that a change in power in favour of retailers would imply that the retailer with increased power should be able to alter the terms of the relationship with a supplier to be more favourable to the retailer over what would have been the case otherwise. If one is interested in examining changes in power from this view over time, the incidence of factors such as the supplier experience curve is relevant. The experience curve suggests that supplier costs over the relevant ranges of volume will always go down, and therefore, over time (assuming that all else remains the same including retail price level), without reductions in price paid by the retailer to the supplier, the supplier would get a larger portion of the joint profitability than at the time the relationship was initiated.

We make no presumption as to whether increased retail power is good or bad. Indeed, there is a literature going back many years discussing the positives and negatives of control by particular segments of the channel (Craig & Gabler 1963). Arguments may be made that increases in retail power in the food industry would be a net benefit to the consumer or a net cost to the consumer. Further, the questions are open as to how much conflict in the channel is desirable to develop the ‘most efficient’ channel, and as to whether or not slotting allowances increase or decrease conflict in the channel over what they would have been otherwise (Bloom et al. 2000, p. 103). Indeed, major suppliers of food (and most industries) have always preferred that retailers reply to their marketing mix with a yes or no, and avoid entering into tough negotiations.

BRIEF ROBINSON-PATMAN SUMMARY

The Robinson-Patman (RP) Act of 1936 is highly relevant to those trying to induce the Federal Trade Commission to regulate slotting allowances in some way (Aalberts & Judd 1991; Skitol 2001). We now give some basics of RP so that one can understand better the evolution of buyer-seller relations in the food industry.

RP, an anti-trust statute, is an amendment to Section 2 of the Clayton Act of 1914. RP makes it unlawful to discriminate in price between different business buyers under certain conditions (Shenefield & Stelzer 1966, p. 77). The discrimination must relate to goods of ‘like grade and quality’. The prices are net of all discounts, rebates and so on (Shenefield & Stelzer 1966, p. 77). Under some conditions, RP also forbids discrimination with respect to brokerage fees, promotion allowances and consideration for services performed. In price discrimination cases, Section 2 of the Sherman Act (attempt to monopolise) and Section 5 of the Federal Trade Commission Act (unfair methods of competition) may be used (Howard 1983, 179).

RP is a confusing law to lawyers, Supreme Court judges, suppliers and retail buyers (Dickinson 1967b). Bork (1978, p. 382) describes it as ‘the misshapen progeny of intolerable draftsmanship’. It contains inherently contradictory goals built upon poorly defined yet important terms such as ‘competition’, ‘costs’ and ‘good faith effort’ (Bork 1978, p. 64). Howard (1983, p. 181) states that there is hardly a phrase or clause of the Act that has gone without litigation as to its proper interpretation.

AN INTERPRETATION OF EVENTS

A scenario is now described that may have caused slotting allowances to come about. There is no way to know if it is ‘true’. However, the scenario is consistent with events and practices described in the literature and also with perceptions of the sector and changes within it. Evidence is offered in the next section that the enforcement of the Robinson-Patman Act changed in the late 1970s and 1980s, during which period slotting allowances in the food industry developed.

In the 1970s there were few important ways for the power of retailers in the food industry to be reflected. The buyers for large food retailers were basically powerful oligopsonists. They were aware of the history of supplier–retailer relationships in the food industry. Generally, the largest suppliers offered a marketing mix and retailers adapted to it in one way or another. Large retailers over time in food had become gun shy, perhaps because RP was enacted primarily as a reaction to concessions obtained by a large supermarket chain (i.e. A&P) that were not generally available to retail competitors. There was no obvious, sizeable part of suppliers’ marketing mixes that could be negotiated without substantial, perceived legal risk.

The overall enforcement environment changed. In the Carter and Reagan administrations (some would include the latter parts of the Ford administration), deregulation was pursued. During the administration of Ronald Reagan, budgets for the enforcement aspects of the Federal Trade Commission were decreased substantially (Stern 1988). New product introductions by suppliers were increasing (Bloom et al. 2000). Some suppliers tested their new products at the retail level as a continuing part of their marketing programmes. Products that did not sell well were discontinued, often at substantial cost to the retailer. Computer systems were becoming increasingly important to the retail enterprise.

Regardless of whether retailers or suppliers initiated slotting allowances, when retailers started to bargain for slotting allowances, the weaker suppliers acquiesced in some form. More powerful supplier firms considered it in terms of their options. If slotting allowances were perceived by the suppliers to be an alternative form of sales promotion, presumably they would be evaluated against the alternatives. Some large suppliers probably saw slotting allowances as a way to increase retail space and as a way to squeeze out competition3. The response of larger firms was undoubtedly highly varied. Today, slotting allowances as a part of a total supplier programme appear to vary with the relative strength of the participating entities (Bloom et al. 2000).

In this new competitive environment, the less powerful suppliers would be expected to acquiesce more readily in the incipient stages, and this may have been an advantage to the retailer in inducing compliance by larger firms. The acceptance by less powerful entities presumably would apply pressure on some of the largest suppliers to adjust to the new competitive environment. Large suppliers could be negotiated with by the use of a new tool that might be seen to be ‘completely’ legal.

The above scenario suggests that the creation of slotting allowances permitted the already large power of the retailer to manifest itself. Slotting allowances as an integral part of the negotiation ‘menu’ were new to the food industry. There were no clear indications as to whether they were legal or illegal. Indeed, there are no clear indications as to their legality today (Federal Trade Commission 2001). Slotting allowances were tried; many suppliers participated. The jury is still out on how long slotting allowances will flourish. The Report of the Federal Trade Commission Workshop on Slotting Allowances and Other Marketing Practices in the Grocery Industry (Federal Trade Commission 2001) maintained that there is continuing consideration of the issue by the Federal Trade Commission.

SOME EVIDENCE

We suggested previously that the enforcement budgets of the Federal Trade Commission were cut substantially at the beginning of the administration of Ronald Reagan. Substantially less money and effort were allocated to enforcement efforts in the 1980s (Stern 1988). Here we present additional evidence of two types. First, we offer changes that occurred in the legal environment to which we have alluded; then we offer some research and commentaries that the evidence for an increase in retail power does not exist.

THE LEGAL ENVIRONMENT

The late 1960s and the 1970s saw a major reversal in the focus of the Federal Trade Commission away from the enforcement of RP (Hollander & Sheffet 1986, p. 767). From 1975 to 1982 the FTC issued only six RP complaints, and from 1983 to 1985 none were issued (Aalberts & Judd 1991, p. 415). Clearly the government was paying less attention to RP and related business activities. Stern (1988) and Bhasin et al.(1989) noted the decrease in the enforcement of RP.

As suggested earlier, Bork (1978) made vicious attacks on RP. He maintained that it did not prevent much price discrimination but did stifle competition, and made substantial efforts to promote the Chicago school of anti-trust, which in many people’s view dominated anti-trust considerations into the 1990s and is strong today (for a discussion and criticism see Hunt & Arnett 2001). The Chicago school suggested that the overwhelming factor to consider in anti-trust matters was consumer welfare, which was to be seen through the prism of neoclassical economics. The focus of enforcement activities was to be on the welfare of the consumer; the behaviour of business participants and the economic structure – the main goals in the development of RP in the 1930s – became less important.

Interest in RP and its provisions and relevance to the food industry increased in the 1980s. The annual research reports of the Progressive Grocer in 1987, 1988, 1989 and 1990 integrated Robinson-Patman Act considerations into their annual survey activities. In the annual research report of 1990 (p. 23), the RP considerations were reflected as being dwarfed by environmental issues. In these yearly surveys there was substantial support for RP among chain executives, wholesalers and manufacturers. There was particularly strong support from co-op wholesalers and small retail chains.

RETAIL POWER DID NOT INCREASE

Retail power – all retailing versus all manufacturing in elements of the food industry – does not appear to have increased. Kelly (1991, p. 197) suggests that slotting allowances could have been a natural marketplace reaction to increased product innovation. Farris and Ailawadi (1992) did not find any increase in retail power in the total sense. Ailawadi (2001) offers a summary of several studies and concludes that the contention that the power of large retailers has increased vis-à-vis packaged goods manufacturers has not been empirically supported. The recent FTC report found little evidence of the existence of (excessive) retail market power (Federal Trade Commission 2001, p. 60).

If an increase in retail power did not induce slotting allowances, what did? Clearly the ‘withdrawal’ of substantial legal constraints may be seen as a strong facilitating factor that permitted the many dimensions of power to be resolved in the marketplace, with slotting allowances being one of the factors.

SO WHAT?

We have made a case for the proposition that, preceding the substantial growth of slotting allowances in the 1970s and 1980s, legal environments changed, and that these legal changes, in the context of increasingly sophisticated and costly technology and a proliferation of new products, created a situation in which slotting allowances could flourish. Retail power, already large, need not have increased relative to supplier power to create this result. In other words, this article suggests that marketing academics and economists appear to have been chasing a ghost: a ghost of increased retail power. Many have tried to encourage government entities to chase the ghost of increased retail power; indeed, the FTC and other government agencies have historically had great flexibility in pursuing or not pursuing activities under RP (Dickinson 1967a)

A key question is: in what way does this change in perspective make a difference? Why should we care?

Perhaps the prime impact of assuming that slotting allowances are manifestations of increased retail power is that many studies have been organised around that assumption. Much effort has been expended to confirm the increase; we go out of our way to look for the rise in power. Since in this view slotting allowances are assumed to be caused by increased and inordinate power (often presumed invidious), many further assume that the symptoms (i.e. slotting allowances) are bad. Increased retail power leads to reduced competition, creates higher retail prices and so on. These inferences, of course, may or may not be ‘true’ depending on many factors. Finally, looking at slotting allowances as derived from an obvious increase in retail power also frames the arguments and attendant research (e.g. Bloom et al. 2000).

OBSERVATIONS

As suggested earlier, other lessons may be drawn from the analysis of slotting allowances offered in this article. The laws and legal frameworks are important for students, faculty and researchers to understand in their varied capacities (Petty 2000). The legal environments can often be critical. Ignorance of them can lead to less than thorough analyses. Further, the complexity of laws such as RP does not diminish their importance or the need to study them, although the complexity and their lack of amenability to mathematical analysis may have been a factor in the decreased academic interest over time.

The same lesson can be drawn with respect to the study of the history of business and its varied environments. It is difficult if not impossible to understand slotting allowances without some understanding of the long history of negotiation in the food industry. Indeed, further insights would probably be offered by studying the interaction of suppliers and retailers in what might be termed the traditional department store industries. Indeed, the FTC vigorously pursued perceived department store violations of RP in the 1950s and 1960s. Further, slotting allowances as defined in the article have been integral to traditional department stores for more than 50 years, although the term ‘slotting allowances’ was not one that was commonly used.

A further inference from an examination of the history of the discussion of slotting allowances is that obvious explanations will dominate without extensive research, and those with vested interests will foster the explanations that support their interests. Further, without substantial independent research, vested industry interests, including those of small business and the legal profession, will tend to dominate the discussion.       

 

REFERENCES

Aalberts, R.J. & Judd, L.L. (1991) Slotting in the retail grocer business: does it violate the public policy goal of protecting businesses against price discrimination? Depaul Law Review, 40, 2 (Winter), pp. 397–416.

Ailawadi, K.L. (2001) The retail power-performance conundrum: what have we learned? Journal of Retailing 77, 3, pp. 299–318.

Bhasin, A., Dickinson, R., Hauri, C.G. & Robinson, W.A. (1989) Promotion investments that keep paying off. Journal of Consumer Marketing, 6, 1 (Winter), pp. 31–36.

Bloom, P.N., Gundlach, G.T. & Cannon, J.P. (2000) Slotting allowances and fees: schools of thought and the views of practicing managers. Journal of Marketing, 64 (April), pp. 92–108.

Bork, R. (1978) The Antitrust Paradox. New York: Basic Books.

Cannon, J.P. & Bloom, P. (1991) Are slotting allowances legal under the antitrust laws? Journal of Public Policy and Marketing, 10, 1 (Spring), pp.167–186.

Craig, D.R. & Gabler, W.K. (1963) The competitive struggle for market control. In Readings in Marketing (Westing, J.E., ed.). Englewood Cliffs, New Jersey: Prentice Hall.

Dickinson, R. (1967a) The FTC – large quality store advertising and the small retailer. California Management Review, Summer, pp. 43–50.

Dickinson, R. (1967b) The retail buyer and the Robinson-Patman Act. California Management Review, Spring, pp. 47–54.

Dickinson, R. & Hollander, S.C. (1996) Some definition problems in marketing channels. Journal of Marketing Channels, 5, 1, pp. 1–15.

Farris, P.W. & Ailawadi, K.L. (1992) Retailer power: monster or mouse. Journal of Retailing, 68, 4, pp. 351–69.

Federal Trade Commission (2001) Report of the Federal Trade Commission Workshop on Slotting Allowances and Other Marketing Practices in the Grocery Industry. Washington, DC: Federal Trade Commission.

Hayes, C.L. (2000) How Coke pushed rivals off the shelf. New York Times, 6 August, section 3, p. 1.

Hollander, S.C. & Sheffet, M. (1996) The Robinson-Patman Act: boon or bane for retailers. The Antitrust Bulletin, 31, 3, pp. 759–795.

Howard, M.C. (1983) Antitrust and Trade Regulation. Englewood Cliffs, New Jersey: Prentice Hall.

Hunt, S.D. & Arnett, D.B. (2001) Competition as an evolutionary process and antitrust policy. Journal of Public Policy and Marketing, 20, 1, pp. 17–20.

Kelly, K. (1991) 'The antitrust analysis of grocery slotting allowances: the pro-competitive case', Journal of Public Policy & Marketing 10, 1, pp. 187-98.

Lariviere, M.A. & Padmanabhan, V. (1997) Slotting allowances and new product introductions. Marketing Science, 16, 2, pp. 112–28.

Petty, R.D. (2000) Teaching marketing law: a business law perspective on integrating marketing and law. Journal of Marketing Education, 22, 2, pp. 129–136.

Progressive Grocer (1987) April, p. 9.

Progressive Grocer (1988) April, p. 9.

Progressive Grocer (1989) April, p. 16.

Progressive Grocer (1990) April, p. 23.

Shenefield, J.H. & Stelzer, I.M. (1966) The Antitrust Laws. Washington, DC: The AEI Press.

Skitol, R.A. (2001) Slotting fee barons: watch your step. American Antitrust Institute Activities, 26 February.

Steiner, R. (1984) Basic relationship in consumer goods industries. In Research in Marketing, volume 7 (Sheth, J., ed.). Greenwich, Connecticut: Jai Press, pp. 165–208.

Steiner, R. (2001) Category management – a pervasive, new vertical/horizontal format. Antitrust, Spring, pp. 77–81.

Stern, L. (1988) Reflections on channels research. Journal of Retailing, 64, 1 (Spring), pp. 1–4.


  1. The recent Report of the Federal Trade Commission Workshop on Slotting Allowances and other Marketing Practices in the Grocery Industry (Federal Trade Commission 2001, p. 29) offers little help on the importance of this marketing practice.

  2. This practice that may be less than lovely is seldom emphasised in marketing texts.

  3. The various soft drink market agreements within the retail industry appear to achieve similar objectives (Hayes 2000).

Roger Dickinson
Roger Dickinson is Professor of Marketing at the University of Texas at Arlington and was previously on the faculties of the University of California at Berkeley and the Rutgers Graduate School of Business. He has had over 100 articles published in refereed journals and proceedings, including the Journal of Business, the Journal of Marketing, the Journal of Retailing, California Management Review and Journal of Consumer Research. He is also author of a new book, Complement to a College Education.



http://www.warc.com
© HAT. All rights reserved.